Article 24 of 54
Cover Story/News: Analysis & Commentary: AFTER THE VERDICT
THE GREAT ANTITRUST DEBATE:
Focus on innovation? Or stick to pricing issues? The outcome is critical
By Michael J. Mandel and Mike France in New York, and Dan Carney in
Washington
06/26/2000
Business Week
Page 40
(Copyright 2000 McGraw-Hill, Inc.)
The war between Microsoft and the Justice Dept. is certainly far from
over. But as the two meet again in court over the appeal of Judge Thomas
Penfield Jackson's decision, there is a parallel intellectual struggle
going on for the soul of antitrust policy. The key issue: Will antitrust
continue to play a limited role in economic policy, as it has for twenty
years? Or will it move to center stage as a key defender of innovation
and innovative firms in the New Economy? This debate has been simmering under the surface for the last few
years, but only recently has it showed up clearly. For most of the
postwar period, trustbusters worried mainly about companies charging
excessive prices. It was generally accepted by both liberal and
conservative economists that monopoly price increases, while they hurt
customers, had relatively little effect on productivity or economic
growth. This was the central tenet of the so-called Chicago School of
antitrust, which dominated policy during the 1980s and held that there
was rarely economic justification for aggressively pursuing antitrust
actions. The result: Regulators were relegated to a peripheral role.
Increasingly, however, the Federal Trade Commission and the Justice
Dept. have been focusing on innovation, not price, as the basis for
antitrust action. Justice's proposal to break up Microsoft was based
primarily on the argument that the company deterred ``innovations that
would truly benefit consumers.'' A similar argument is being made in the
antitrust case against Visa USA and MasterCard International Inc. that
just went to trial. And the FTC and Justice recently issued guidelines
for collaboration between rivals which paid special attention to the
impact on innovation. If the innovation-based approach to antitrust becomes widely
accepted, it would greatly broaden the mandate of antitrust regulators.
Unlike higher prices from monopoly, impediments to innovation in a
market can have a direct impact on overall productivity and growth in
the economy. ``Innovation becomes more and more the engine that drives
consumer welfare,'' says FTC Chairman Robert Pitofsky. ``In many ways,
innovation is the heart of the new economy.'' Nevertheless, there is real resistance to focusing on innovation as a
key goal of antitrust policy. While antitrust economists generally agree
that innovation is important, they worry that it may be hard to devise
good remedies, or identify cases where innovation is hurt by market
power. ``People don't even have an informed guess about what
concentration does to innovation,'' says Stephen Calkins, antitrust
professor at Wayne State University School of Law, who served as FTC
general counsel. The new approach also has to win the approval of skeptical judges who
have been trained for years to think in terms of relatively narrow
economic rationales for antitrust intervention. In particular, it is not
clear whether the government's proposed breakup of Microsoft--primarily
based on the claim that it will boost innovation--can survive the appeal
(page 42). But whether or not the government ultimately wins the
Microsoft case, there are powerful forces working in favor of the new
approach--chief of which has to be the pivotal role innovation plays in
the continued expansion of the New Economy. In a time of rapid
technological change, notes Frederic M. Scherer, a leading antitrust
economist at Harvard University, ``it's very important to maintain a
level playing field [to] spark innovation.'' The new approach draws a direct link between antitrust policy and
macroeconomic performance. ``It used to be thought that the
industrial-policy economies, in Asia and in Europe, would be the
powerhouses of the 21st century,'' says Assistant Attorney General Joel
I. Klein. ``It is now clear that the most competitive economies will
throw off the most innovation and the most dynamic growth.'' And antitrust regulators have been seeing more and more cases in
which innovation plays a crucial role. That trend, rather than a Chicago
School-style framework, shaped how Pitofsky and Klein began to evaluate
cases, including Microsoft. At the same time, innovation has been
receiving increasing attention within the economics profession, after
years of being treated as a relatively unimportant sub-field. When Klein
needed someone to write a brief supporting the Microsoft break-up, he
chose Paul Romer, the Stanford economist widely credited with
revitalizing the study of growth and innovation in the 1980s. Still, the new approach faces many criticisms, chief among them its
speculative and somewhat ad hoc nature. Research into antitrust and
innovation remains inconclusive. Indeed, there is little clear-cut
evidence on whether small companies or large companies have a better
track record with innovation. Small companies can generate new ideas
without worrying about corporate bureaucracies or existing products. Big
companies have the advantage of sufficient resources for research and
product development. But it may very well be that in an era of relatively free-flowing
venture capital, the resource advantage of big companies is less
important. For the first time, it is possible for young, innovative
companies to raise large sums and immediately challenge existing rivals.
Thus, the New Economy model of innovation is the continual birth of
startups that either grow big themselves or get snapped up by bigger
fish. As economists focus on innovation, they may uncover principles to
guide antitrust policy. ``Even on relatively easy stuff like price,
there is still a lot of debate,'' says Harvey J. Goldschmid, professor
of antitrust law at Columbia University. ``But you can get research, and
over time reach a consensus. You may get the same consensus over time on
innovation.'' INSTANT ISSUE. One possibility, advanced by economists
such as Romer, is that innovation will be squashed if big companies can
choke off entry by new rivals. Consider instant messaging, for example.
Much of the Internet's success has been the product of its openness to
new applications. But America Online Inc., with the largest number of
instant-message users by far, has consistently tried to keep other
companies from tapping into its network, citing security concerns. The
latest example: AOL recently blocked users of Odigo, a new type of
instant-messaging software, from communicating with users of America
Online instant-messaging software. AOL notes that it has royalty-free
licensing agreements with more than a dozen companies that have agreed
to abide by AOL's consumer privacy and security protections. Still, the
FTC has asked AOL for more info on the blockage as part of its review of
the AOL-Time Warner merger. The innovation-based approach to antitrust also means focusing
especially on industries where possible collusion between competitors
may be holding up innovation. For example, in the case against Visa and
MasterCard, the government alleges MasterCard shelved plans to develop a
``smart card''--a credit card with a microprocessor--because Visa
decided not to go ahead with a similar product. When it comes to mergers in research-intensive industries such as
pharmaceuticals, it may be appropriate to intensify the already close
scrutiny of overlaps in R&D. Indeed, one recent study by CenterWatch, a
newsletter that monitors the clinical trials industry, found
clinical-research spending and the number of development projects
declined sharply in the three years following a merger. Tough as it is to know how and when to apply innovation criteria, a
bigger problem may be crafting workable remedies. Success in high-tech
industries often depends on network effects in which consumers get most
value from joining the network with the largest market share. The
problem: Even if the company got its commanding position through
anti-competitive acts, consumers might not benefit from a breakup of the
monopoly. ``Winner-take-most-markets is a natural phenomenon,'' says
Nicholas S. Economides , an economist at New York University's Stern
School of Business. ``This has not really been recognized by the
lawyers.'' The ongoing American Airlines predatory-pricing case, while not based
on innovation, also highlights the obstacles to real remedies. The
government alleges the airline cut fares to drive out small competitors
from its Dallas-Fort Worth hub, then jacked prices up again. Is the
government ``going to prevent American from adding capacity or lowering
fares?'' asks George Washington University antitrust Professor William
E. Kovacic. Any such rules, Kovacic says, would hurt consumers. In this
case, remedies would almost certainly have to be merely punitive, coming
after the elimination of rivals. In addition, it's still unclear if courts or future administrations
will accept the government's new theories. The Supreme Court's last
major antitrust opinion, in '97, was decided 9-0 based on Chicago-school
antitrust reasoning. And the appeals court that will likely hear
Microsoft's case has shown no sign of being open to the broader
innovation arguments. The political environment is not necessarily conducive to an
innovation-based antitrust policy either. George W. Bush, who earlier
this year noted that the main legitimate role for antitrust is in
preventing price-fixing, has been getting advice that current antitrust
policy is too expansive, says former FTC Chairman James C. Miller III.
Even more frustrating for Klein and Pitofsky, no one even in the Clinton
Administration has made a more activist antitrust policy part of a
broader political agenda. Without political consensus, survival of the
new theories becomes less likely. Still, the New Antitrust has a
powerful ally in the New Economy and its dependence on innovation. And
as long as regulators continue to detect efforts to cut off ideas or
their access to markets, the new antitrust will continue to take shape. (See related article: "WILL THE APPEAL HOLD WATER?" -- BusinessWeek
June 26, 2000)
|